Professor/Lecturer Ellmann's Course Materials Page

fix the Fed
Home
microeconomics
FREEDOM
macroeconomics
economic thought
MBA/MA - Anglo-American University International Finance
ERASMUS - International Finance
MBA - Money and Financial Markets
ERASMUS Money & Banking
M.A. Public Policy Economic Sociology
Ethics
On the Origin of Facts

Fixing the Fed
  by William Greider


Congress and the Obama administration face an excruciating dilemma. To
restore the crippled financial system, they are told, they must put up
still more public money--hundreds of billions more--to rescue the
largest banks and investment houses from failure. Even the dimmest
politicians realize that this will further inflame the public's anger.
People everywhere grasp that there is something morally wrong about
bailing out the malefactors who caused this catastrophe. Yet we are told
we have no choice. Unless taxpayers assume the losses for the largest
financial institutions by buying their rotten assets, the banking
industry will not resume normal lending and, therefore, the economy
cannot recover.

This is a false dilemma. Other choices are available. Throwing more
public money at essentially insolvent banks is like giving blood
transfusions to a corpse and hoping for Lazarus--or, as banking analyst
Christopher Whalen puts it, pouring water into a bucket with a hole in
the bottom. So far Washington has poured nearly $300 billion into the
bucket, and Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner has suggested it may
take another $1 trillion or more to complete the banks' resurrection.
The president has budgeted $750 billion for the task. Morality aside,
that sounds nutty.

Here is a very different way to understand the problem: to restore the
broken financial system, Washington has to fix the Federal Reserve.
Though this is not widely understood, the central bank has lost its
ability to govern the credit system--the nation's overall lending and
borrowing. The Fed's control mechanisms have been severely undermined by
a generation of deregulation and tricky innovations that have
substantially shifted credit functions from traditional banks to lightly
regulated financial markets. When the Fed tried to apply its old tools,
starting in the 1980s, the credit system perversely produced opposite
results--an explosion of debt the policy-makers could not restrain. In
its present condition, the Fed may even make things worse.

Instead of frankly acknowledging the problem, Fed governors proceeded in
the past two decades to engineer exaggerated swings in monetary
policy--raising interest rates, then lowering them, in widening
extremes. This led to the series of bubbles in financial prices--first
stocks, then housing and commodities--that collapsed with devastating
consequences, climaxing in the present crisis. In other words, the
central bank's weakened condition and its misguided policy decisions
have been a central factor in destabilizing the American economy. More
to the point, the Fed's operating disorders are directly threatening to
recovery; the economy is not likely to get well if the dysfunctional Fed
is not also reformed.

In this crisis the central bank has so far flooded credit markets and
financial institutions with trillions of dollars in new liquidity and
loan guarantees, which may help to stabilize credit markets. But the Fed
has been unable to engineer what the economy desperately needs--renewed
lending to companies and consumers that can finance renewed growth. The
confused purpose of monetary policy stands in the way. The Fed could not
restrain credit expansion when it was exploding, and now it cannot
stimulate credit expansion when it is frozen.

This analysis is drawn from the work of Jane D'Arista, a reform-minded
economist and retired professor with a deep conceptual understanding of
money and credit.  (Read her recent essay, "Setting an Agenda for Monetary Reform.") D'Arista proposes operating reforms at the central
bank that would be powerfully stimulative for the economy and would also
restore the Fed's role as the moderating governor of the credit system.
The Fed, she argues, must create a system of control that will cover not
only the commercial banks it already regulates but also the unregulated
nonbank financial firms and funds that dispense credit in the "shadow
banking system," like hedge funds and private equity firms. These and
other important pools of capital displaced traditional bank lending with
market securities and collaborated with major banks in evading
prudential rules and regulatory limits. "Shadow banking" is, likewise,
frozen by crisis.

Once the central bank has established balance sheet connections to all
the important financial institutions, including insurance companies and
mutual funds, it can engineer the balance sheet conditions that will
virtually compel them to unfreeze lending and restart the flows of
credit. This does not require spending vast sums of taxpayers' money. It
does require the government to abandon the pretense that it is merely
assisting troubled private enterprises in these difficult times.
Government has to step up to this financial crisis and take charge of
the solution, regardless of how it disposes of the so-called zombie
banks. Otherwise, Washington, including the Fed, will be restoring a
dysfunctional system that can lead to the same scandalous errors.

D'Arista, who taught at Boston University and years ago was on the staff
of the House banking committee, is barely known among exalted
policy-makers. But her work has a strong following among progressive
economists, who recognize the originality of her thinking. For nearly
fifteen years with the Financial Markets Center, a monetary policy think
tank, D'Arista identified the systemic disorders emerging in domestic
and international finance. She proposed timely reforms while admiring
economists congratulated the Fed for creating an era of "great
moderation." D'Arista, I should add, is also a published poet. Formal
economists will scoff, but poets often see realities the bean counters
fail to recognize.

Leaning With the Wind

To understand D'Arista's reform ideas, start with her devastating
critique of the central bank. The Federal Reserve, she explains, has
failed in its most essential function: to serve as the balance wheel
that keeps economic cycles from going too far. It is supposed to be a
moderating force in American capitalism on the upside and on the
downside, the role popularly described as "leaning against the wind." By
applying its leverage on the available supply of credit, the Fed can
slow down a boom that is dangerously overwrought or, likewise, stimulate
the economy if it is sinking into recession. The Fed's job, a former
chairman once joked, is "to take away the punch bowl just when the party
gets going." Economists know this function as "counter-cyclical policy."

The Fed not only lost control, D'Arista asserts, but its policy actions
have unintentionally become "pro-cyclical"--encouraging financial
excesses instead of countering the extremes. "The pattern that has
developed over the last two decades," she wrote in 2008, "suggests that
relying on changes in interest rates as the primary tool of monetary
policy can set off pro-cyclical foreign capital flows that tend to
reverse the intended result of the action taken. As a result, monetary
policy can no longer reliably perform its counter-cyclical function--its
raison d'être--and its attempts to do so may exacerbate
instability."

Anyone familiar with the back-and-forth swings of monetary policy during
recent years will recognize her point. On repeated occasions, the Fed
set out to tighten the availability of credit but was, in effect,
overruled by the credit markets, which instead expanded their lending
and borrowing. The central bank would raise short-term interest rates to
slow things down, only to see long-term borrowing rates fall in
financial markets and negate the Fed's impact. These recurring
contradictions were familiar to financial players but not to the general
public. Fed chair Paul Volcker was stymied by expanding credit when he
raised rates in 1982-84. His successor, Alan Greenspan, experienced the
same frustration in 1994-95 (the beginning of the great debt bubble) and
again at the end of the decade. The contradiction became more visible in
2005: Greenspan kept raising short-term interest rates in gradual steps,
yet long-term rates kept falling, feeding the bubble of borrowing and
inflating prices.

"Rather than restore its ability to exert direct influence over credit
expansion and contraction," D'Arista wrote, "the Fed adhered to outdated
tools and policies that became increasingly counterproductive. Too often
its actions tended to exacerbate cyclical behavior in financial markets
rather than exert countercyclical influence." (For her full critique,
read "Setting an Agenda for Monetary Reform," a 2008 lecture at the Levy
Economics Institute of Bard College, posted online at the Political
Economy Research Institute's website. )

Most politicians do not even know the Fed is broken. The central bank's
awesome authority is an intimidating mystery to most elected officials,
and they typically defer to its oracular pronouncements. But the Federal
Reserve, like all human institutions, is subject to folly and error. In
fact, it has experienced colossal failure once before in its history.
After the stock market crash of 1929, the Fed was utterly disgraced
because its response led directly to the Great Depression. Fed governors
were motivated by conservative orthodoxy and their desire to protect the
profitability of the largest banks, but they misunderstood the mechanics
of monetary policy and also stuck to outdated theory that produced the
disastrous results. D'Arista's analysis is chilling because she suggests
the modern central bank, albeit in very different circumstances, may
again be pursuing wrongheaded theory, blinded by similar political
biases and obsolete doctrine (for the history, see my book Secrets of
the Temple: How the Federal Reserve Runs the Country).

When deregulation began nearly thirty years ago, some leading Fed
governors, including Volcker, were aware that it would weaken the Fed's
hand, and they grumbled privately. The 1980 repeal of interest-rate
limits meant the central bank would have to apply the brakes longer and
harder to get any response from credit markets. "The only restraining
influence you have left is interest rates," one influential governor
complained to me, "restraint that works ultimately by bankrupting the
customer." Yet the Fed supported deregulation, partly because its most
important constituency, Wall Street banking and finance, pushed for it
relentlessly. Working Americans felt greater pain as a result. The
central bank braked the real economy's normal growth continually in a
roundabout attempt to slow down the credit markets.

The central bank was undermined more gravely by further deregulation,
which encouraged the migration of lending functions from traditional
bank loans to market securities, like the bundled mortgage securities
that are now rotten assets. Greenspan became an aggressive advocate of
the so-called modernization that created Citigroup and the other
hybridized mega-banks--the ones in deep trouble. Old-line banks lost
market share to nonbanks, but they were allowed to collaborate with
unregulated market players as a way to evade the limits on borrowing and
risk-taking. In 1977 commercial banks held 56 percent of all financial
assets. By 2007 the banking share had fallen to 24 percent.

The shrinkage meant the Fed was trying to control credit through a much
smaller base of lending institutions. It failed utterly--witness the
soaring debt burden and subsequent defaults. Greenspan, celebrated as
the wise wizard, never acknowledged Wall Street's inflation of debt.
Indeed, he attempted to slow down the economy in order to constrain the
financial system's bubbles. That did not succeed either. As
Nation readers may recall, I have more than once blistered the
Fed's inept performance and blamed Greenspan's "free-market" ideological
bias [see "The One-Eyed Chairman," September 19, 2005]. D'Arista's
analysis goes deeper and attributes the systemic malfunctioning to the
Fed's weakened control mechanisms.

Central bankers attempted to fix the problem, but they may have made it
worse. In the late '80s, the Fed and Wall Street leaders, joined by
foreign central banks, created an international regulatory regime that
requires banks to hold greater levels of capital instead of bank
reserves. Reserves are the Fed's traditional cushion for ensuring the
"safety and soundness" of the system. Banks were required to post
non-interest-bearing accounts on their balance sheets to backstop
deposits and as the means for the central bank to brake bank lending. It
was assumed that the new capital requirements would do the same.
Instead, the so-called Basel Accords (named for the Bank of
International Settlements in Basel, Switzerland) applied very little
restraint on lending but created an unintended vulnerability for
banking. The new rules have acted like a pro-cyclical force--driving
banks into a deeper hole as the crisis has spread because bank capital
is destroyed directly by the mounting losses from market securities. The
more banks lose on their rotten assets, the more capital they have to
borrow from wary investors, who understandably refuse to play. That
spreads the panic and failure that governments are trying to cure with
public money.

Meanwhile, acting at the behest of bankers, the Fed has practically
eliminated the old safety cushion by allowing reserve levels to fall
nearly to zero. Bankers complained that reserves were a drag on profits
and were no longer needed given the capital rules. In a shocking new
arrangement, the Fed, with approval from Congress, has started to pay
interest to the banks on their reserves. The commercial banks already
enjoyed privileges and protections from the government that were
unavailable to any other business sector. Now they insist on getting
paid for their public subsidy.

How to Restore Credit--and Credibility

In the past six months, the Fed seems to have reversed course, because
bank reserves suddenly jumped tenfold in September, then doubled again
by December. Skeptics may conclude that it has created a safe haven for
bankers. When everything else is collapsing, banks are given risk-free
assets by the Fed; then they collect income from the central bank
instead of lending the funds to risky customers. If reserve balances
keep growing, the deal will begin to look like hoarding.

These distorted arrangements are what D'Arista thinks must be changed to
break out of the downward spiral. The all-encompassing requirement she
proposes--liability reserves--would give the central bank the mechanism
to inject stimulus into the credit system, into banks and nonbanks
alike, funding the Fed can withdraw later if the economy no longer needs
a boost. The Fed would first purchase a variety of sound financial
instruments from the lending institutions and create an interest-free
account that would be posted as a "liability" on the institutions'
balance sheets--an obligation owed to the Fed. In order to balance this
liability against the loss of income-earning assets on their books, the
banks and other firms would have to use the Fed-injected money to make
new loans to companies and consumers or to other banks. Either way, the
Fed injection would spur lending and help unlock the paralysis in credit
markets.

In this arrangement, the Fed would remain in control, because all these
transactions would be covered by a repurchase agreement requiring the
bank to buy back what it sold to the Fed, on a fixed date and at the
same price. The Fed could demand its money back or renew the repurchase
contract at its choosing (a standard practice in Fed open-market
operations). Thus, if the bank does nothing with its newly injected
funds to create loans and generate more income, it will be in trouble
when the repurchase contract comes due. The Fed is likewise inhibited
from buying worthless junk from banks because that would ruin its
balance sheet, the base for the money supply. Instead of earning
risk-free income by holding idle reserves, the banking industry would
abruptly feel the lash of the central bank's policy decisions--open up
your wallets and start lending to more borrowers, or face consequences
down the road.

But where does the Fed find the money to make all these transactions?
Essentially, it creates the money. That is basically what occurs
routinely whenever the central bank decides to inject new reserves into
the banking system. It is accomplished with a computer keystroke
crediting the money to the private bank's account (and money is
extinguished whenever the Fed withdraws reserves). The mystery of money
creation defies common reason, but it works because people believe in
the results. The money supply relies on the "full faith and credit" of
the society at large--pure credit from the people who use the currency.
The public's faith can be enlisted in the national recovery, a far
better option than spending the hard-earned money that comes from
taxpayers.

D'Arista's solution would create the scaffolding to impose many other
regulations on the behavior of lending and borrowing. But it does not
resolve the problem of what to do with zombie banks. Some of them
deserve to die--right now--because they are "too big to save," as the
Levy Institute puts it. Other institutions in trouble can be tightly
supervised by regulators for years to come, without relieving them of
their rotten assets. This will require a kind of silent forbearance that
lets the bankers slowly work off their losses, but it does not dump the
losses on the public. D'Arista points out that the government has done
this many times in the past. The closest comparison is the Third World
debt crisis during the 1980s, when some of the same major banks were
under water as Latin American nations threatened massive loan defaults.
A lengthy, methodical workout was managed by the Fed under Paul Volcker.
It wasn't pretty, nor was it just, but the public was not really aware
of the deal-making. This time, the deal is too big to hide. People see
it happening and are rightly enraged.

The great virtue of D'Arista's approach is that it's forward-looking.
Her focus is not on saving the largest and most culpable names at the
pinnacle of the financial system but on creating the platform for a
financial order composed of thousands of smaller, more deserving
institutions that can serve the country more reliably. To achieve this,
the Federal Reserve will have to submit to its own reckoning. By its
very design, the cloistered central bank is an offense to democratic
principles--and now the Fed's secretive, unaccountable political power
has failed democracy again. The question of how to democratize the
temple or whether to tear it down has to be on the table too, the
subject of future discussion.



This article can be found on the web at:

http://www.thenation.com/doc/20090330/greider

Enter supporting content here