Finance
Wall Street Lays Another Egg
Not so long ago, the dollar stood for a sum of gold, and bankers knew the people they lent to. The
author charts the emergence of an abstract, even absurd world—call it Planet Finance—where mathematical models
ignored both history and human nature, and value had no meaning. by Niall Ferguson December 2008 Illustration by
Tim Bower
The bigger they come: Uncle Sam and Wall Street take the hardest fall since the Depression. Illustration
by Tim Bower.
This year we have lived through something more than a financial crisis. We have witnessed the death
of a planet. Call it Planet Finance. Two years ago, in 2006, the measured economic output of the entire world was worth
around $48.6 trillion. The total market capitalization of the world's stock markets was $50.6 trillion, 4 percent larger.
The total value of domestic and international bonds was $67.9 trillion, 40 percent larger. Planet Finance was beginning
to dwarf Planet Earth.
Planet Finance seemed to spin faster, too. Every day $3.1 trillion changed hands on foreign-exchange
markets. Every month $5.8 trillion changed hands on global stock markets. And all the time new financial life-forms
were evolving. The total annual issuance of mortgage-backed securities, including fancy new "collateralized debt obligations" (C.D.O.'s),
rose to more than $1 trillion. The volume of "derivatives"—contracts such as options and swaps—grew even faster,
so that by the end of 2006 their notional value was just over $400 trillion. Before the 1980s, such things were virtually
unknown. In the space of a few years their populations exploded. On Planet Finance, the securities outnumbered the people;
the transactions outnumbered the relationships. Illustration by Brad Holland
Read Niall Ferguson's prescient
article on today's financial woes, Empire Falls (November 2006).
New institutions also proliferated. In 1990 there
were just 610 hedge funds, with $38.9 billion under management. At the end of 2006 there were 9,462, with $1.5 trillion
under management. Private-equity partnerships also went forth and multiplied. Banks, meanwhile, set up a host of "conduits"
and "structured investment vehicles" (sivs—surely the most apt acronym in financial history) to keep potentially
risky assets off their balance sheets. It was as if an entire shadow banking system had come into being.
Then,
beginning in the summer of 2007, Planet Finance began to self-destruct in what the International Monetary Fund soon acknowledged
to be "the largest financial shock since the Great Depression." Did the crisis of 2007–8 happen because American companies
had gotten worse at designing new products? Had the pace of technological innovation or productivity growth suddenly slackened? No.
The proximate cause of the economic uncertainty of 2008 was financial: to be precise, a crunch in the credit markets triggered
by mounting defaults on a hitherto obscure species of housing loan known euphemistically as "subprime mortgages."
Central
banks in the United States and Europe sought to alleviate the pressure on the banks with interest-rate cuts and offers
of funds through special "term auction facilities." Yet the market rates at which banks could borrow money, whether
by issuing commercial paper, selling bonds, or borrowing from one another, failed to follow the lead of the official
federal-funds rate. The banks had to turn not only to Western central banks for short-term assistance to rebuild their
reserves but also to Asian and Middle Eastern sovereign-wealth funds for equity injections. When these sources proved insufficient, investors—and
speculative short-sellers—began to lose faith.
Beginning with Bear Stearns, Wall Street's investment banks entered
a death spiral that ended with their being either taken over by a commercial bank (as Bear was, followed by Merrill
Lynch) or driven into bankruptcy (as Lehman Brothers was). In September the two survivors—Goldman Sachs and Morgan
Stanley—formally ceased to be investment banks, signaling the death of a business model that dated back to the
Depression. Other institutions deemed "too big to fail" by the U.S. Treasury were effectively taken over by the government, including
the mortgage lenders and guarantors Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac and the insurance giant American International Group (A.I.G.).
By
September 18 the U.S. financial system was gripped by such panic that the Treasury had to abandon this ad hoc policy. Treasury Secretary
Henry Paulson hastily devised a plan whereby the government would be authorized to buy "troubled" securities with up to
$700 billion of taxpayers' money—a figure apparently plucked from the air. When a modified version of the measure
was rejected by Congress 11 days later, there was panic. When it was passed four days after that, there was more panic.
Now it wasn't just bank stocks that were tanking. The entire stock market seemed to be in free fall as fears mounted
that the credit crunch was going to trigger a recession. Moreover, the crisis was now clearly global in scale. European
banks were in much the same trouble as their American counterparts, while emerging-market stock markets were crashing.
A week of frenetic improvisation by national governments culminated on the weekend of October 11–12, when the
United States reluctantly followed the British government's lead, buying equity stakes in banks rather than just their
dodgy assets and offering unprecedented guarantees of banks' debt and deposits.
Since these events coincided with
the final phase of a U.S. presidential-election campaign, it was not surprising that some rather simplistic lessons
were soon being touted by candidates and commentators. The crisis, some said, was the result of excessive deregulation
of financial markets. Others sought to lay the blame on unscrupulous speculators: short-sellers, who borrowed the stocks
of vulnerable banks and sold them in the expectation of further price declines. Still other suspects in the frame were
negligent regulators and corrupt congressmen.
This hunt for scapegoats is futile. To understand the downfall of Planet
Finance, you need to take several steps back and locate this crisis in the long run of financial history. Only then will
you see that we have all played a part in this latest sorry example of what the Victorian journalist Charles Mackay
described in his 1841 book, Extraordinary Popular Delusions and the Madness of Crowds. Nothing New
As long as
there have been banks, bond markets, and stock markets, there have been financial crises. Banks went bust in the days of
the Medici. There were bond-market panics in the Venice of Shylock's day. And the world's first stock-market crash happened
in 1720, when the Mississippi Company—the Enron of its day—blew up. According to economists Carmen Reinhart
and Kenneth Rogoff, the financial history of the past 800 years is a litany of debt defaults, banking crises, currency
crises, and inflationary spikes. Moreover, financial crises seldom happen without inflicting pain on the wider economy.
Another recent paper, co-authored by Rogoff's Harvard colleague Robert Barro, has identified 148 crises since 1870 in
which a country experienced a cumulative decline in gross domestic product (G.D.P.) of at least 10 percent, implying
a probability of financial disaster of around 3.6 percent per year.
If stock-market movements followed the normal-distribution,
or bell, curve, like human heights, an annual drop of 10 percent or more would happen only once every 500 years, whereas
in the case of the Dow Jones Industrial Average it has happened in 20 of the last 100 years. And stock-market plunges
of 20 percent or more would be unheard of—rather like people a foot and a half tall—whereas in fact there have
been eight such crashes in the past century.
The most famous financial crisis—the Wall Street Crash—is conventionally
said to have begun on "Black Thursday," October 24, 1929, when the Dow declined by 2 percent, though in fact the market had
been slipping since early September and had suffered a sharp, 6 percent drop on October 23. On "Black Monday," October
28, it plunged by 13 percent, and the next day by a further 12 percent. In the course of the next three years the U.S.
stock market declined by a staggering 89 percent, reaching its nadir in July 1932. The index did not regain its 1929
peak until November 1954.
That helps put our current troubles into perspective. From its peak of 14,164, on October
9, 2007, to a dismal level of 8,579, exactly a year later, the Dow declined by 39 percent. By contrast, on a single day just
over two decades ago—October 19, 1987—the index fell by 23 percent, one of only four days in history when the
index has fallen by more than 10 percent in a single trading session.
This crisis, however, is about much more than
just the stock market. It needs to be understood as a fundamental breakdown of the entire financial system, extending
from the monetary-and-banking system through the bond market, the stock market, the insurance market, and the real-estate
market. It affects not only established financial institutions such as investment banks but also relatively novel ones such
as hedge funds. It is global in scope and unfathomable in scale.
Had it not been for the frantic efforts of the Federal
Reserve and the Treasury, to say nothing of their counterparts in almost equally afflicted Europe, there would by now
have been a repeat of that "great contraction" of credit and economic activity that was the prime mover of the Depression.
Back then, the Fed and the Treasury did next to nothing to prevent bank failures from translating into a drastic contraction
of credit and hence of business activity and employment. If the more openhanded monetary and fiscal authorities of today
are ultimately successful in preventing a comparable slump of output, future historians may end up calling this "the
Great Repression." This is the Depression they are hoping to bottle up—a Depression in denial.
To understand
why we have come so close to a rerun of the 1930s, we need to begin at the beginning, with banks and the money they make. From
the Middle Ages until the mid-20th century, most banks made their money by maximizing the difference between the costs
of their liabilities (payments to depositors) and the earnings on their assets (interest and commissions on loans).
Some banks also made money by financing trade, discounting the commercial bills issued by merchants. Others issued and
traded bonds and stocks, or dealt in commodities (especially precious metals). But the core business of banking was simple.
It consisted, as the third Lord Rothschild pithily put it, "essentially of facilitating the movement of money from Point
A, where it is, to Point B, where it is needed."
The system evolved gradually. First came the invention of cashless intra-bank
and inter-bank transactions, which allowed debts to be settled between account holders without having money physically
change hands. Then came the idea of fractional-reserve banking, whereby banks kept only a small proportion of their
existing deposits on hand to satisfy the needs of depositors (who seldom wanted all their money simultaneously), allowing
the rest to be lent out profitably. That was followed by the rise of special public banks with monopolies on the issuing
of banknotes and other powers and privileges: the first central banks.
With these innovations, money ceased to be
understood as precious metal minted into coins. Now it was the sum total of specific liabilities (deposits and reserves)
incurred by banks. Credit was the other side of banks' balance sheets: the total of their assets; in other words, the
loans they made. Some of this money might still consist of precious metal, though a rising proportion of that would be held
in the central bank's vault. Most would be made up of banknotes and coins recognized as "legal tender," along with money
that was visible only in current- and deposit-account statements.
Until the late 20th century, the system of bank
money retained an anchor in the pre-modern conception of money in the form of the gold standard: fixed ratios between
units of account and quantities of precious metal. As early as 1924, the English economist John Maynard Keynes dismissed
the gold standard as a "barbarous relic," but the last vestige of the system did not disappear until August 15, 1971—the day
President Richard Nixon closed the so-called gold window, through which foreign central banks could still exchange dollars
for gold. With that, the centuries-old link between money and precious metal was broken.
Though we tend to think
of money today as being made of paper, in reality most of it now consists of bank deposits. If we measure the ratio
of actual money to output in developed economies, it becomes clear that the trend since the 1970s has been for that ratio
to rise from around 70 percent, before the closing of the gold window, to more than 100 percent by 2005. The corollary
has been a parallel growth of credit on the other side of bank balance sheets. A significant component of that credit
growth has been a surge of lending to consumers. Back in 1952, the ratio of household debt to disposable income was
less than 40 percent in the United States. At its peak in 2007, it reached 133 percent, up from 90 percent a decade before. Today
Americans carry a total of $2.56 trillion in consumer debt, up by more than a fifth since 2000.
Even more spectacular,
however, has been the rising indebtedness of banks themselves. In 1980, bank indebtedness was equivalent to 21 percent
of U.S. gross domestic product. In 2007 the figure was 116 percent. Another measure of this was the declining capital adequacy
of banks. On the eve of "the Great Repression," average bank capital in Europe was equivalent to less than 10 percent
of assets; at the beginning of the 20th century, it was around 25 percent. It was not unusual for investment banks'
balance sheets to be as much as 20 or 30 times larger than their capital, thanks in large part to a 2004 rule change
by the Securities and Exchange Commission that exempted the five largest of those banks from the regulation that had capped
their debt-to-capital ratio at 12 to 1. The Age of Leverage had truly arrived for Planet Finance.
Credit and
money, in other words, have for decades been growing more rapidly than underlying economic activity. Is it any wonder,
then, that money has ceased to hold its value the way it did in the era of the gold standard? The motto "In God we trust"
was added to the dollar bill in 1957. Since then its purchasing power, relative to the consumer price index, has declined
by a staggering 87 percent. Average annual inflation during that period has been more than 4 percent. A man who decided
to put his savings into gold in 1970 could have bought just over 27.8 ounces of the precious metal for $1,000. At the time
of writing, with gold trading at $900 an ounce, he could have sold it for around $25,000.
Those few goldbugs
who always doubted the soundness of fiat money—paper currency without a metal anchor—have in large measure
been vindicated. But why were the rest of us so blinded by money illusion? Blowing Bubbles
In the immediate aftermath
of the death of gold as the anchor of the monetary system, the problem of inflation affected mainly retail prices and
wages. Today, only around one out of seven countries has an inflation rate above 10 percent, and only one, Zimbabwe, is
afflicted with hyperinflation. But back in 1979 at least 7 countries had an annual inflation rate above 50 percent,
and more than 60 countries—including Britain and the United States—had inflation in double digits.
Inflation
has come down since then, partly because many of the items we buy—from clothes to computers—have gotten cheaper
as a result of technological innovation and the relocation of production to low-wage economies in Asia. It has also
been reduced because of a worldwide transformation in monetary policy, which began with the monetarist-inspired increases
in short-term rates implemented by the Federal Reserve in 1979. Just as important, some of the structural drivers of
inflation, such as powerful trade unions, have also been weakened.
By the 1980s, in any case, more and more people
had grasped how to protect their wealth from inflation: by investing it in assets they expected to appreciate in line
with, or ahead of, the cost of living. These assets could take multiple forms, from modern art to vintage wine, but
the most popular proved to be stocks and real estate. Once it became clear that this formula worked, the Age of Leverage
could begin. For it clearly made sense to borrow to the hilt to maximize your holdings of stocks and real estate if
these promised to generate higher rates of return than the interest payments on your borrowings. Between 1990 and 2004,
most American households did not see an appreciable improvement in their incomes. Adjusted for inflation, the median
household income rose by about 6 percent. But people could raise their living standards by borrowing and investing in stocks
and housing.
Nearly all of us did it. And the bankers were there to help. Not only could they borrow more cheaply
from one another than we could borrow from them; increasingly they devised all kinds of new mortgages that looked more
attractive to us (and promised to be more lucrative to them) than boring old 30-year fixed-rate deals. Moreover, the banks were
just as ready to play the asset markets as we were. Proprietary trading soon became the most profitable arm of investment
banking: buying and selling assets on the bank's own account. Illustration by Barry Blitt
Losing our shirt? The
problem is that our banks are also losing theirs. Illustration by Barry Blitt.
There was, however, a catch. The
Age of Leverage was also an age of bubbles, beginning with the dot-com bubble of the irrationally exuberant 1990s and
ending with the real-estate mania of the exuberantly irrational 2000s. Why was this?
The future is in large measure
uncertain, so our assessments of future asset prices are bound to vary. If we were all calculating machines, we would
simultaneously process all the available information and come to the same conclusion. But we are human beings, and as such
are prone to myopia and mood swings. When asset prices surge upward in sync, it is as if investors are gripped by a
kind of collective euphoria. Conversely, when their "animal spirits" flip from greed to fear, the bubble that their
earlier euphoria inflated can burst with amazing suddenness. Zoological imagery is an integral part of the culture of Planet
Finance. Optimistic buyers are "bulls," pessimistic sellers are "bears." The real point, however, is that stock markets
are mirrors of the human psyche. Like Homo sapiens, they can become depressed. They can even suffer complete breakdowns.
This
is no new insight. In the 400 years since the first shares were bought and sold on the Amsterdam Beurs, there has been
a long succession of financial bubbles. Time and again, asset prices have soared to unsustainable heights only to crash
downward again. So familiar is this pattern—described by the economic historian Charles Kindleberger—that
it is possible to distill it into five stages:
(1) Displacement: Some change in economic circumstances creates new and
profitable opportunities. (2) Euphoria, or overtrading: A feedback process sets in whereby expectation of rising profits
leads to rapid growth in asset prices. (3) Mania, or bubble: The prospect of easy capital gains attracts first-time
investors and swindlers eager to mulct them of their money. (4) Distress: The insiders discern that profits cannot possibly
justify the now exorbitant price of the assets and begin to take profits by selling. (5) Revulsion, or discredit: As asset
prices fall, the outsiders stampede for the exits, causing the bubble to burst.
The key point is that without easy
credit creation a true bubble cannot occur. That is why so many bubbles have their origins in the sins of omission and
commission of central banks.
The bubbles of our time had their origins in the aftermath of the 1987 stock-market
crash, when then novice Federal Reserve chairman Alan Greenspan boldly affirmed the Fed's "readiness to serve as a source
of liquidity to support the economic and financial system." This sent a signal to the markets, particularly the New
York banks: if things got really bad, he stood ready to bail them out. Thus was born the "Greenspan put"—the implicit
option the Fed gave traders to be able to sell their stocks at today's prices even in the event of a meltdown tomorrow.
Having
contained a panic once, Greenspan thereafter had a dilemma lurking in the back of his mind: whether or not to act pre-emptively the
next time—to prevent a panic altogether. This dilemma came to the fore as a classic stock-market bubble took shape
in the mid-90s. The displacement in this case was the explosion of innovation by the technology and software industry
as personal computers met the Internet. But, as in all of history's bubbles, an accommodative monetary policy also played
a role. From a peak of 6 percent in February 1995, the federal-funds target rate had been reduced to 5.25 percent by
January 1996. It was then cut in steps, in the fall of 1998, down to 4.75 percent, and it remained at that level until
June 1999, by which time the Dow had passed the 10,000 mark.
Why did the Fed allow euphoria to run loose in the
1990s? Partly because Greenspan and his colleagues underestimated the momentum of the technology bubble; as early as
December 1995, with the Dow just past the 5,000 mark, members of the Fed's Open Market Committee speculated that the
market might be approaching its peak. Partly, also, because Greenspan came to the conclusion that it was not the Fed's
responsibility to worry about asset-price inflation, only consumer-price inflation, and this, he believed, was being reduced
by a major improvement in productivity due precisely to the tech boom.
Greenspan could not postpone a stock-exchange
crash indefinitely. After Silicon Valley's dot-com bubble peaked, in March 2000, the U.S. stock market fell by almost
half over the next two and a half years. It was not until May 2007 that investors in the Standard & Poor's 500 had
recouped their losses. But the Fed's response to the sell-off—and the massive shot of liquidity it injected into
the financial markets after the 9/11 terrorist attacks—prevented the "correction" from precipitating a depression.
Not only were the 1930s averted; so too, it seemed, was a repeat of the Japanese experience after 1989, when a conscious
effort by the central bank to prick an asset bubble had ended up triggering an 80 percent stock-market sell-off, a real-estate collapse,
and a decade of economic stagnation.
What was not immediately obvious was that Greenspan's easy-money policy was
already generating another bubble—this time in the financial market that a majority of Americans have been encouraged
for generations to play: the real-estate market. The American Dream
Real estate is the English-speaking world's
favorite economic game. No other facet of financial life has such a hold on the popular imagination. The real-estate
market is unique. Every adult, no matter how economically illiterate, has a view on its future prospects. Through the
evergreen board game Monopoly, even children are taught how to climb the property ladder.
Once upon a time, people
saved a portion of their earnings for the proverbial rainy day, stowing the cash in a mattress or a bank safe. The Age
of Leverage, as we have seen, brought a growing reliance on borrowing to buy assets in the expectation of their future appreciation
in value. For a majority of families, this meant a leveraged investment in a house. That strategy had one very obvious flaw.
It represented a one-way, totally unhedged bet on a single asset.
To be sure, investing in housing paid off handsomely
for more than half a century, up until 2006. Suppose you had put $100,000 into the U.S. property market back in the
first quarter of 1987. According to the Case-Shiller national home-price index, you would have nearly tripled your money
by the first quarter of 2007, to $299,000. On the other hand, if you had put the same money into the S&P 500, and had continued
to re-invest the dividend income in that index, you would have ended up with $772,000 to play with—more than double
what you would have made on bricks and mortar.
There is, obviously, an important difference between a house and
a stock-market index. You cannot live in a stock-market index. For the sake of a fair comparison, allowance must therefore
be made for the rent you save by owning your house (or the rent you can collect if you own a second property). A simple
way to proceed is just to leave out both dividends and rents. In that case the difference is somewhat reduced. In the
two decades after 1987, the S&P 500, excluding dividends, rose by a factor of just over six, meaning that an investment
of $100,000 would be worth some $600,000. But that still comfortably beat housing.
There are three other considerations
to bear in mind when trying to compare housing with other forms of assets. The first is depreciation. Stocks do not
wear out and require new roofs; houses do. The second is liquidity. As assets, houses are a great deal more expensive to convert
into cash than stocks. The third is volatility. Housing markets since World War II have been far less volatile than stock markets.
Yet that is not to say that house prices have never deviated from a steady upward path. In Britain between 1989 and 1995,
for example, the average house price fell by 18 percent, or, in inflation-adjusted terms, by more than a third—37
percent. In London, the real decline was closer to 47 percent. In Japan between 1990 and 2000, property prices fell
by more than 60 percent.
The recent decline of property prices in the United States should therefore have come as
less of a shock than it did. Between July 2006 and June 2008, the Case-Shiller index of home prices in 20 big American
cities declined on average by 19 percent. In some of these cities—Phoenix, San Diego, Los Angeles, and Miami—the
total decline was as much as a third. Seen in international perspective, those are not unprecedented figures. Seen in
the context of the post-2000 bubble, prices have yet to return to their starting point. On average, house prices are
still 50 percent higher than they were at the beginning of this process.
So why were we oblivious to the likely
bursting of the real-estate bubble? The answer is that for generations we have been brainwashed into thinking that borrowing
to buy a house is the only rational financial strategy to pursue. Think of Frank Capra's classic 1946 movie, It's a
Wonderful Life, which tells the story of the family-owned Bailey Building & Loan, a small-town mortgage firm that George
Bailey (played by James Stewart) struggles to keep afloat in the teeth of the Depression. "You know, George," his father
tells him, "I feel that in a small way we are doing something important. It's satisfying a fundamental urge. It's deep
in the race for a man to want his own roof and walls and fireplace, and we're helping him get those things in our shabby
little office." George gets the message, as he passionately explains to the villainous slumlord Potter after Bailey Sr.'s
death: "[My father] never once thought of himself.… But he did help a few people get out of your slums, Mr. Potter.
And what's wrong with that? … Doesn't it make them better citizens? Doesn't it make them better customers?"
There,
in a nutshell, is one of the key concepts of the 20th century: the notion that property ownership enhances citizenship,
and that therefore a property-owning democracy is more socially and politically stable than a democracy divided into
an elite of landlords and a majority of property-less tenants. So deeply rooted is this idea in our political culture
that it comes as a surprise to learn that it was invented just 70 years ago. Fannie, Ginnie, and Freddie
Prior
to the 1930s, only a minority of Americans owned their homes. During the Depression, however, the Roosevelt administration
created a whole complex of institutions to change that. A Federal Home Loan Bank Board was set up in 1932 to encourage
and oversee local mortgage lenders known as savings-and-loans (S&Ls)—mutual associations that took in deposits
and lent to homebuyers. Under the New Deal, the Home Owners' Loan Corporation stepped in to refinance mortgages on longer terms,
up to 15 years. To reassure depositors, who had been traumatized by the thousands of bank failures of the previous three years,
Roosevelt introduced federal deposit insurance. And by providing federally backed insurance for mortgage lenders, the Federal Housing
Administration (F.H.A.) sought to encourage large (up to 80 percent of the purchase price), long (20- to 25-year), fully amortized,
low-interest loans.
By standardizing the long-term mortgage and creating a national system of official inspection
and valuation, the F.H.A. laid the foundation for a secondary market in mortgages. This market came to life in 1938, when
a new Federal National Mortgage Association—nicknamed Fannie Mae—was authorized to issue bonds and use the
proceeds to buy mortgages from the local S&Ls, which were restricted by regulation both in terms of geography (they
could not lend to borrowers more than 50 miles from their offices) and in terms of the rates they could offer (the so-called
Regulation Q, which imposed a low ceiling on interest paid on deposits). Because these changes tended to reduce the average
monthly payment on a mortgage, the F.H.A. made home ownership viable for many more Americans than ever before. Indeed,
it is not too much to say that the modern United States, with its seductively samey suburbs, was born with Fannie Mae.
Between 1940 and 1960, the home-ownership rate soared from 43 to 62 percent.
These were not the only ways in which
the federal government sought to encourage Americans to own their own homes. Mortgage-interest payments were always
tax-deductible, from the inception of the federal income tax in 1913. As Ronald Reagan said when the rationality of this
tax break was challenged, mortgage-interest relief was "part of the American dream."
In 1968, to broaden the
secondary-mortgage market still further, Fannie Mae was split in two—the Government National Mortgage Association
(Ginnie Mae), which was to cater to poor borrowers, and a rechartered Fannie Mae, now a privately owned government-sponsored enterprise
(G.S.E.). Two years later, to provide competition for Fannie Mae, the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation (Freddie Mac) was
set up. In addition, Fannie Mae was permitted to buy conventional as well as government-guaranteed mortgages. Later, with
the Community Reinvestment Act of 1977, American banks found themselves under pressure for the first time to lend to
poor, minority communities.
These changes presaged a more radical modification to the New Deal system. In the late
1970s, the savings-and-loan industry was hit first by double-digit inflation and then by sharply rising interest rates. This
double punch was potentially lethal. The S&Ls were simultaneously losing money on long-term, fixed-rate mortgages,
due to inflation, and hemorrhaging deposits to higher-interest money-market funds. The response in Washington from both
the Carter and Reagan administrations was to try to salvage the S&Ls with tax breaks and deregulation. When the
new legislation was passed, President Reagan declared, "All in all, I think we hit the jackpot." Some people certainly
did.
On the one hand, S&Ls could now invest in whatever they liked, not just local long-term mortgages. Commercial
property, stocks, junk bonds—anything was allowed. They could even issue credit cards. On the other, they could
now pay whatever interest rate they liked to depositors. Yet all their deposits were still effectively insured, with
the maximum covered amount raised from $40,000 to $100,000, thanks to a government regulation two years earlier. And if
ordinary deposits did not suffice, the S&Ls could raise money in the form of brokered deposits from middlemen. What
happened next perfectly illustrated the great financial precept first enunciated by William Crawford, the commissioner
of the California Department of Savings and Loan: "The best way to rob a bank is to own one." Some S&Ls bet their depositors'
money on highly dubious real-estate developments. Many simply stole the money, as if deregulation meant that the law no longer
applied to them at all.
When the ensuing bubble burst, nearly 300 S&Ls collapsed, while another 747 were closed
or reorganized under the auspices of the Resolution Trust Corporation, established by Congress in 1989 to clear up the
mess. The final cost of the crisis was $153 billion (around 3 percent of the 1989 G.D.P.), of which taxpayers had to pay
$124 billion.
But even as the S&Ls were going belly-up, they offered another, very different group of American
financial institutions a fast track to megabucks. To the bond traders at Salomon Brothers, the New York investment bank,
the breakdown of the New Deal mortgage system was not a crisis but a wonderful opportunity. As profit-hungry as their language
was profane, the self-styled "Big Swinging Dicks" at Salomon saw a way of exploiting the gyrating interest rates of the
early 1980s.
The idea was to re-invent mortgages by bundling thousands of them together as the backing for new
and alluring securities that could be sold as alternatives to traditional government and corporate bonds—in short,
to convert mortgages into bonds. Once lumped together, the interest payments due on the mortgages could be subdivided into
strips with different maturities and credit risks. The first issue of this new kind of mortgage-backed security (known
as a "collateralized mortgage obligation") occurred in June 1983. The dawn of securitization was a necessary prelude
to the Age of Leverage.
Once again, however, it was the federal government that stood ready to pick up the tab in
a crisis. For the majority of mortgages continued to enjoy an implicit guarantee from the government-sponsored trio of Fannie,
Freddie, and Ginnie, meaning that bonds which used those mortgages as collateral could be represented as virtual government bonds
and considered "investment grade." Between 1980 and 2007, the volume of such G.S.E.-backed mortgage-backed securities grew
from less than $200 billion to more than $4 trillion. In 1980 only 10 percent of the home-mortgage market was securitized;
by 2007, 56 percent of it was.
These changes swept away the last vestiges of the business model depicted in It's
a Wonderful Life. Once there had been meaningful social ties between mortgage lenders and borrowers. James Stewart's character
knew both the depositors and the debtors. By contrast, in a securitized market the interest you paid on your mortgage ultimately went
to someone who had no idea you existed. The full implications of this transition for ordinary homeowners would become apparent
only 25 years later. The Lessons of Detroit
In July 2007, I paid a visit to Detroit, because I had the feeling that
what was happening there was the shape of things to come in the United States as a whole. In the space of 10 years, house
prices in Detroit, which probably possesses the worst housing stock of any American city other than New Orleans, had
risen by more than a third—not much compared with the nationwide bubble, but still hard to explain, given the
city's chronically depressed economic state. As I discovered, the explanation lay in fundamental changes in the rules of the
housing game.
I arrived at the end of a borrowing spree. For several years agents and brokers selling subprime mortgages
had been flooding Detroit with radio, television, and direct-mail advertisements, offering what sounded like attractive
deals. In 2006, for example, subprime lenders pumped more than a billion dollars into 22 Detroit Zip Codes.
These
were not the old 30-year fixed-rate mortgages invented in the New Deal. On the contrary, a high proportion were adjustable-rate mortgages—in
other words, the interest rate could vary according to changes in short-term lending rates. Many were also interest-only mortgages,
without amortization (repayment of principal), even when the principal represented 100 percent of the assessed value of
the mortgaged property. And most had introductory "teaser" periods, whereby the initial interest payments—usually
for the first two years—were kept artificially low, with the cost of the loan backloaded. All of these devices
were intended to allow an immediate reduction in the debt-servicing costs of the borrower.
In Detroit only a minority
of these loans were going to first-time buyers. They were nearly all refinancing deals, which allowed borrowers to treat
their homes as cash machines, converting their existing equity into cash and using the proceeds to pay off credit-card
debts, carry out renovations, or buy new consumer durables. However, the combination of declining long-term interest rates
and ever more alluring mortgage deals did attract new buyers into the housing market. By 2005, 69 percent of all U.S. householders were
homeowners; 10 years earlier it had been 64 percent. About half of that increase could be attributed to the subprime-lending
boom.
Significantly, a disproportionate number of subprime borrowers belonged to ethnic minorities. Indeed, I found
myself wondering, as I drove around Detroit, if "subprime" was in fact a new financial euphemism for "black." This was
no idle supposition. According to a joint study by, among others, the Massachusetts Affordable Housing Alliance, 55
percent of black and Latino borrowers in Boston who had obtained loans for single-family homes in 2005 had been given subprime mortgages;
the figure for white borrowers was just 13 percent. More than three-quarters of black and Latino borrowers from Washington Mutual
were classed as subprime, whereas only 17 percent of white borrowers were. According to a report in The Wall Street Journal, minority
ownership increased by 3.1 million between 2002 and 2007.
Here, surely, was the zenith of the property-owning democracy.
It was an achievement that the Bush administration was proud of. "We want everybody in America to own their own home,"
President George W. Bush had said in October 2002. Having challenged lenders to create 5.5 million new minority homeowners
by the end of the decade, Bush signed the American Dream Downpayment Act in 2003, a measure designed to subsidize first-time
house purchases in low-income groups. Between 2000 and 2006, the share of undocumented subprime contracts rose from 17
to 44 percent. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac also came under pressure from the Department of Housing and Urban Development
to support the subprime market. As Bush put it in December 2003, "It is in our national interest that more people own
their own home." Few people dissented.
As a business model, subprime lending worked beautifully—as long, that is,
as interest rates stayed low, people kept their jobs, and real-estate prices continued to rise. Such conditions could not
be relied upon to last, however, least of all in a city like Detroit. But that did not worry the subprime lenders. They
simply followed the trail blazed by mainstream mortgage lenders in the 1980s. Having pocketed fat commissions on the
signing of the original loan contracts, they hastily resold their loans in bulk to Wall Street banks. The banks, in
turn, bundled the loans into high-yielding mortgage-backed securities and sold them to investors around the world, all
eager for a few hundredths of a percentage point more of return on their capital. Repackaged as C.D.O.'s, these subprime securities
could be transformed from risky loans to flaky borrowers into triple-A-rated investment-grade securities. All that was
required was certification from one of the rating agencies that at least the top tier of these securities was unlikely
to go into default.
The risk was spread across the globe, from American state pension funds to public-hospital networks
in Australia, to town councils near the Arctic Circle. In Norway, for example, eight municipalities, including Rana
and Hemnes, invested some $120 million of their taxpayers' money in C.D.O.'s secured on American subprime mortgages.
In
Detroit the rise of subprime mortgages had in fact coincided with a new slump in the inexorably declining automobile industry.
That anticipated a wider American slowdown, an almost inevitable consequence of a tightening of monetary policy as the
Federal Reserve belatedly raised short-term interest rates from 1 percent to 5.25 percent. As soon as the teaser rates
expired and mortgages were reset at new and much higher interest rates, hundreds of Detroit households swiftly fell
behind in their mortgage payments. The effect was to burst the real-estate bubble, causing house prices to start falling significantly
for the first time since the early 1990s. And the further house prices fell, the more homeowners found themselves with "negative
equity"—in other words, owing more money than their homes were worth.
The rest—the chain reaction as
defaults in Detroit and elsewhere unleashed huge losses on C.D.O.'s in financial institutions all around the world—you
know. Drunk on Derivatives
Do you, however, know about the second-order effects of this crisis in the markets
for derivatives? Do you in fact know what a derivative is? Once excoriated by Warren Buffett as "financial weapons of mass destruction,"
derivatives are what make this crisis both unique and unfathomable in its ramifications. To understand what they are, you need,
literally, to go back to the future.
For a farmer planting a crop, nothing is more crucial than the future price
it will fetch after it has been harvested and taken to market. A futures contract allows him to protect himself by committing
a merchant to buy his crop when it comes to market at a price agreed upon when the seeds are being planted. If the market
price on the day of delivery is lower than expected, the farmer is protected.
The earliest forms of protection for
farmers were known as forward contracts, which were simply bilateral agreements between seller and buyer. A true futures
contract, however, is a standardized instrument issued by a futures exchange and hence tradable. With the development of
a standard "to arrive" futures contract, along with a set of rules to enforce settlement and, finally, an effective clearinghouse,
the first true futures market was born.
Because they are derived from the value of underlying assets, all futures
contracts are forms of derivatives. Closely related, though distinct from futures, are the contracts known as options.
In essence, the buyer of a "call" option has the right, but not the obligation, to buy an agreed-upon quantity of a
particular commodity or financial asset from the seller ("writer") of the option at a certain time (the expiration date)
for a certain price (known as the "strike price"). Clearly, the buyer of a call option expects the price of the underlying
instrument to rise in the future. When the price passes the agreed-upon strike price, the option is "in the money"—and
so is the smart guy who bought it. A "put" option is just the opposite: the buyer has the right but not the obligation
to sell an agreed-upon quantity of something to the seller of the option at an agreed-upon price.
A third kind
of derivative is the interest-rate "swap," which is effectively a bet between two parties on the future path of interest rates.
A pure interest-rate swap allows two parties already receiving interest payments literally to swap them, allowing someone
receiving a variable rate of interest to exchange it for a fixed rate, in case interest rates decline. A credit-default
swap (C.D.S.), meanwhile, offers protection against a company's defaulting on its bonds. Illustration by Brad Holland
Bringing
down the bull: The pain of America's financial crisis is felt all over the world. Illustration by Brad Holland.
There
was a time when derivatives were standardized instruments traded on exchanges such as the Chicago Board of Trade. Now,
however, the vast proportion are custom-made and sold "over the counter" (O.T.C.), often by banks, which charge attractive
commissions for their services, but also by insurance companies (notably A.I.G.). According to the Bank for International
Settlements, the total notional amounts outstanding of O.T.C. derivative contracts—arranged on an ad hoc basis between
two parties—reached a staggering $596 trillion in December 2007, with a gross market value of just over $14.5 trillion.
But
how exactly do you price a derivative? What precisely is an option worth? The answers to those questions required a revolution
in financial theory. From an academic point of view, what this revolution achieved was highly impressive. But the events
of the 1990s, as the rise of quantitative finance replaced preppies with quants (quantitative analysts) all along Wall
Street, revealed a new truth: those whom the gods want to destroy they first teach math.
Working closely with Fischer
Black, of the consulting firm Arthur D. Little, M.I.T.'s Myron Scholes invented a groundbreaking new theory of pricing
options, to which his colleague Robert Merton also contributed. (Scholes and Merton would share the 1997 Nobel Prize in economics.)
They reasoned that a call option's value depended on six variables: the current market price of the stock (S), the agreed future
price at which the stock could be bought (L), the time until the expiration date of the option (t), the risk-free rate
of return in the economy as a whole (r), the probability that the option will be exercised (N), and—the crucial
variable—the expected volatility of the stock, i.e., the likely fluctuations of its price between the time of purchase
and the expiration date (s). With wonderful mathematical wizardry, the quants reduced the price of a call option to this formula
(the Black-Scholes formula):
in which:
Feeling a bit baffled? Can't follow the algebra? That was just fine by the
quants. To make money from this magic formula, they needed markets to be full of people who didn't have a clue about how
to price options but relied instead on their (seldom accurate) gut instincts. They also needed a great deal of computing
power, a force which had been transforming the financial markets since the early 1980s. Their final requirement was
a partner with some market savvy in order to make the leap from the faculty club to the trading floor. Black, who would
soon be struck down by cancer, could not be that partner. But John Meriwether could. The former head of the bond-arbitrage
group at Salomon Brothers, Meriwether had made his first fortune in the wake of the S&L meltdown of the late 1980s.
The hedge fund he created with Scholes and Merton in 1994 was called Long-Term Capital Management.
In its brief,
four-year life, Long-Term was the brightest star in the hedge-fund firmament, generating mind-blowing returns for its elite club
of investors and even more money for its founders. Needless to say, the firm did more than just trade options, though selling
puts on the stock market became such a big part of its business that it was nicknamed "the central bank of volatility"
by banks buying insurance against a big stock-market sell-off. In fact, the partners were simultaneously pursuing multiple
trading strategies, about 100 of them, with a total of 7,600 positions. This conformed to a second key rule of the new
mathematical finance: the virtue of diversification, a principle that had been formalized by Harry M. Markowitz, of the
Rand Corporation. Diversification was all about having a multitude of uncorrelated positions. One might go wrong, or
even two. But thousands just could not go wrong simultaneously.
The mathematics were reassuring. According to the
firm's "Value at Risk" models, it would take a 10-s (in other words, 10-standard-deviation) event to cause the firm
to lose all its capital in a single year. But the probability of such an event, according to the quants, was 1 in 10,24—or
effectively zero. Indeed, the models said the most Long-Term was likely to lose in a single day was $45 million. For
that reason, the partners felt no compunction about leveraging their trades. At the end of August 1997, the fund's capital was
$6.7 billion, but the debt-financed assets on its balance sheet amounted to $126 billion, a ratio of assets to capital
of 19 to 1.
There is no need to rehearse here the story of Long-Term's downfall, which was precipitated by a Russian
debt default. Suffice it to say that on Friday, August 21, 1998, the firm lost $550 million—15 percent of its
entire capital, and vastly more than its mathematical models had said was possible. The key point is to appreciate why
the quants were so wrong.
The problem lay with the assumptions that underlie so much of mathematical finance.
In order to construct their models, the quants had to postulate a planet where the inhabitants were omniscient and perfectly
rational; where they instantly absorbed all new information and used it to maximize profits; where they never stopped trading; where
markets were continuous, frictionless, and completely liquid. Financial markets on this planet followed a "random walk,"
meaning that each day's prices were quite unrelated to the previous day's, but reflected no more and no less than all
the relevant information currently available. The returns on this planet's stock market were normally distributed along
the bell curve, with most years clustered closely around the mean, and two-thirds of them within one standard deviation
of the mean. On such a planet, a "six standard deviation" sell-off would be about as common as a person shorter than one
foot in our world. It would happen only once in four million years of trading.
But Long-Term was not located on
Planet Finance. It was based in Greenwich, Connecticut, on Planet Earth, a place inhabited by emotional human beings,
always capable of flipping suddenly and en masse from greed to fear. In the case of Long-Term, the herding problem was
acute, because many other firms had begun trying to copy Long-Term's strategies in the hope of replicating its stellar performance.
When things began to go wrong, there was a truly bovine stampede for the exits. The result was a massive, synchronized downturn
in virtually all asset markets. Diversification was no defense in such a crisis. As one leading London hedge-fund manager later
put it to Meriwether, "John, you were the correlation."
There was, however, another reason why Long-Term failed. The
quants' Value at Risk models had implied that the loss the firm suffered in August 1998 was so unlikely that it ought
never to have happened in the entire life of the universe. But that was because the models were working with just five
years of data. If they had gone back even 11 years, they would have captured the 1987 stock-market crash. If they had
gone back 80 years they would have captured the last great Russian default, after the 1917 revolution. Meriwether himself,
born in 1947, ruefully observed, "If I had lived through the Depression, I would have been in a better position to understand
events." To put it bluntly, the Nobel Prize winners knew plenty of mathematics but not enough history.
One might
assume that, after the catastrophic failure of L.T.C.M., quantitative hedge funds would have vanished from the financial
scene, and derivatives such as options would be sold a good deal more circumspectly. Yet the very reverse happened.
Far from declining, in the past 10 years hedge funds of every type have exploded in number and in the volume of assets
they manage, with quantitative hedge funds such as Renaissance, Citadel, and D. E. Shaw emerging as leading players.
The growth of derivatives has also been spectacular—and it has continued despite the onset of the credit crunch.
Between December 2005 and December 2007, the notional amounts outstanding for all derivatives increased from $298 trillion
to $596 trillion. Credit-default swaps quadrupled, from $14 trillion to $58 trillion.
An intimation of the problems
likely to arise came in September, when the government takeover of Fannie and Freddie cast doubt on the status of derivative
contracts protecting the holders of more than $1.4 trillion of their bonds against default. The consequences of the failure
of Lehman Brothers were substantially greater, because the firm was the counter-party in so many derivative contracts.
The
big question is whether those active in the market waited too long to set up some kind of clearing mechanism. If, as seems
inevitable, there is an upsurge in corporate defaults as the U.S. slides into recession, the whole system could completely
seize up. The China Syndrome
Just 10 years ago, during the Asian crisis of 1997–98, it was conventional
wisdom that financial crises were more likely to happen on the periphery of the world economy—in the so-called emerging markets
of East Asia and Latin America. Yet the biggest threats to the global financial system in this new century have come not
from the periphery but from the core. The explanation for this strange role reversal may in fact lie in the way emerging
markets changed their behavior after 1998.
For many decades it was assumed that poor countries could become rich only
by borrowing capital from wealthy countries. Recurrent debt crises and currency crises associated with sudden withdrawals
of Western money led to a rethinking, inspired largely by the Chinese example.
When the Chinese wanted to attract
foreign capital, they insisted that it take the form of direct investment. That meant that instead of borrowing from
Western banks to finance its industrial development, as many emerging markets did, China got foreigners to build factories
in Chinese enterprise zones—large, lumpy assets that could not easily be withdrawn in a crisis.
The crucial
point, though, is that the bulk of Chinese investment has been financed from China's own savings. Cautious after years
of instability and unused to the panoply of credit facilities we have in the West, Chinese households save a high proportion
of their rising incomes, in marked contrast to Americans, who in recent years have saved almost none at all. Chinese
corporations save an even larger proportion of their soaring profits. The remarkable thing is that a growing share of
that savings surplus has ended up being lent to the United States. In effect, the People's Republic of China has become banker
to the United States of America.
The Chinese have not been acting out of altruism. Until very recently, the best
way for China to employ its vast population was by exporting manufactured goods to the spendthrift U.S. consumer. To ensure
that those exports were irresistibly cheap, China had to fight the tendency for its currency to strengthen against the
dollar by buying literally billions of dollars on world markets. In 2006, Chinese holdings of dollars reached 700 billion.
Other Asian and Middle Eastern economies adopted much the same strategy.
The benefits for the United States were
manifold. Asian imports kept down U.S. inflation. Asian labor kept down U.S. wage costs. Above all, Asian savings kept
down U.S. interest rates. But there was a catch. The more Asia was willing to lend to the United States, the more Americans
were willing to borrow. The Asian savings glut was thus the underlying cause of the surge in bank lending, bond issuance,
and new derivative contracts that Planet Finance witnessed after 2000. It was the underlying cause of the hedge-fund
population explosion. It was the underlying reason why private-equity partnerships were able to borrow money left, right,
and center to finance leveraged buyouts. And it was the underlying reason why the U.S. mortgage market was so awash with
cash by 2006 that you could get a 100 percent mortgage with no income, no job, and no assets.
Whether or not China
is now sufficiently "decoupled" from the United States that it can insulate itself from our credit crunch remains to be
seen. At the time of writing, however, it looks very doubtful. Back to Reality
The modern financial system is the
product of centuries of economic evolution. Banks transformed money from metal coins into accounts, allowing ever larger
aggregations of borrowing and lending. From the Renaissance on, government bonds introduced the securitization of streams
of interest payments. From the 17th century on, equity in corporations could be bought and sold in public stock markets.
From the 18th century on, central banks slowly learned how to moderate or exacerbate the business cycle. From the 19th
century on, insurance was supplemented by futures, the first derivatives. And from the 20th century on, households were
encouraged by government to skew their portfolios in favor of real estate. Illustration by Brad Holland
Read
Niall Ferguson's prescient article on today's financial woes, Empire Falls (November 2006).
Economies that combined
all these institutional innovations performed better over the long run than those that did not, because financial intermediation
generally permits a more efficient allocation of resources than, say, feudalism or central planning. For this reason, it
is not wholly surprising that the Western financial model tended to spread around the world, first in the guise of imperialism,
then in the guise of globalization.
Yet money's ascent has not been, and can never be, a smooth one. On the contrary,
financial history is a roller-coaster ride of ups and downs, bubbles and busts, manias and panics, shocks and crashes.
The excesses of the Age of Leverage—the deluge of paper money, the asset-price inflation, the explosion of consumer
and bank debt, and the hypertrophic growth of derivatives—were bound sooner or later to produce a really big crisis.
It
remains unclear whether this crisis will have economic and social effects as disastrous as those of the Great Depression,
or whether the monetary and fiscal authorities will succeed in achieving a Great Repression, averting a 1930s-style
"great contraction" of credit and output by transferring the as yet unquantifiable losses from banks to taxpayers.
Either
way, Planet Finance has now returned to Planet Earth with a bang. The key figures of the Age of Leverage—the lax
central bankers, the reckless investment bankers, the hubristic quants—are now feeling the full force of this
planet's gravity.
But what about the rest of us, the rank-and-file members of the deluded crowd? Well, we shall
now have to question some of our most deeply rooted assumptions—not only about the benefits of paper money but
also about the rationale of the property-owning democracy itself.
On Planet Finance it may have made sense to borrow
billions of dollars to finance a massive speculation on the future prices of American houses, and then to erect on the
back of this trade a vast inverted pyramid of incomprehensible securities and derivatives.
But back here on Planet
Earth it suddenly seems like an extraordinary popular delusion.
Niall Ferguson is Laurence A. Tisch Professor of
History at Harvard University and a Senior Fellow of the Hoover Institution at Stanford, and the author of The War of
the World: Twentieth-Century Conflict and the Descent of the West.
Reply |
|
Forward |
|
|
|
|