The firm's primary objective in producing output is to maximize profits. The production of output, however, involves certain costs that reduce the profits a firm can make. The relationship between costs and profits is therefore critical to the firm's determination of how much output to produce.
Explicit and implicit costs. A firm's explicit costs comprise all
explicit payments to the factors of production the firm uses. Wages paid to workers, payments to suppliers of raw materials,
and fees paid to bankers and lawyers are all included among the firm's explicit costs. A firm's implicit costs consist of
the opportunity costs of using the firm's own resources without receiving any explicit compensation
for those resources. For example, a firm that uses its own building for production purposes forgoes the income that it might
receive from renting the building out. As another example, consider the owner of a firm who works along with his employees
but does not draw a salary; the owner forgoes the opportunity to earn a wage working for someone else. These implicit costs
are not regarded as costs in an accounting sense, but they are a part of the firm's costs of doing business, nonetheless.
When economists discuss costs, they have in mind both explicit and implicit costs. Accounting profits, economic profits, and normal profits. The difference
between explicit and implicit costs is crucial to understanding the difference between accounting profits and economic profits. Accounting
profits are the firm's total revenues from sales of its output, minus the firm's explicit costs. Economic
profits are total revenues minus explicit and implicit costs. Alternatively stated, economic profits are accounting
profits minus implicit costs. Thus, the difference between economic profits and accounting profits is that economic profits
include the firm's implicit costs and accounting profits do not. A firm is said to make normal profits when its
economic profits are zero. The fact that economic profits are zero implies
that the firm's reserves are enough to cover the firm's explicit costs and all of its implicit costs, such as the rent that
could be earned on the firm's building or the salary the owner of the firm could earn elsewhere. These implicit costs add
up to the profits the firm would normally receive if it were properly compensated for the use of its own resources—hence
the name, normal profits. Fixed and variable costs. In the short-run, some of the input factors the firm uses in production
are fixed. The cost of these fixed factors are the firm's fixed costs. The firm's fixed costs do
not vary with increases in the firm's output. The firm also employs a number of variable factors of production. The cost of these variable
factors of production are the firm's variable costs. In order to increase output, the firm must
increase the number of variable factors of production that it employs. Therefore, as firm output increases, the firm's variable
costs must also increase. To illustrate the concepts of fixed and variable costs, consider again the example of a single firm operating in
the short-run with a fixed amount of capital, 1 unit, and a variable amount of labor. Suppose the cost of the single unit
of capital is $100 and the cost of hiring each worker is $20. The firm's fixed and variable costs are reported in Table 1 . Labor input Capital input Total product Variable cost Fixed cost Total cost Marginal cost 0 1 0 $0 $100 $100 - 1 1 5 20 100 120 $4.0 2 1 15 40 100 140 2.0 3 1 23 60 100 160 2.5 4 1 27 80 100 180 5.0 5 1 29 100 100 200 10.0 6 1 30 120 100 220 20.0 The fourth column of Table 1 reports the variable cost that the firm incurs from hiring 1 to 6 workers at $20 each, while the fifth column reports
the fixed cost of the single unit of capital that the firm employs. The fixed cost of $100 is the same—no matter how
many units of output the firm produces. Total and marginal costs. The firm's total cost of
production is the sum of all its variable and fixed costs. The firm's marginal
cost is the per unit change in total cost that results from a change in
total product. The concepts of total and marginal cost are illustrated in Table 1 . The sixth column of this table reports the firm's total costs, which are simply the sum of its variable and fixed
costs. The seventh column reports the marginal cost associated with different levels of output. For example, when the firm increases its
total product from 0 to 5 units of output, the change in the firm's total costs is $120 – $100 = $20. The marginal cost
for the first 5 units of output is therefore $20/5 = $4. Similarly, when the firm increases its total product by 10 units,
from 5 to 15 units of output, its total costs increase by $140 - $120 = $20. The marginal cost for the next 10 units produced
is therefore $20/10 = $2. Marginal cost and marginal product. The firm's marginal cost is
related to its marginal product. If one calculates the change in total cost for each different
level of total product reported and divides by the corresponding marginal product of labor reported, one arrives at the marginal
cost figure. The marginal cost falls at first, then starts to rise. This behavior is a consequence of the relationship between
marginal cost and marginal product and the law of diminishing returns. As the marginal product of the variable input–labor– rises, the firm's total product incresses at a rate that is greater than the rate of new
workers hired. Consequently, the firm's marginal costs will be decreasing. Eventually, however, by the law of diminishing
returns, the marginal product of the variable factor will begin to decline; the firm's total product will increase at a rate
less than the rate at which new workers are hired. The result is that the firm's marginal costs will begin rising. Average variable, average fixed,
and average total costs. The firm's variable, fixed, and total costs can all be calculated on an average or per unit basis. Table 2 reports the average variable costs, average fixed costs, and average total costs for
the numerical example of Table 1 . Total product Average variable cost Average fixed cost Average total cost 0 — — — 5 $4.00 $20.00 $24.00 15 2.66 6.66 9.33 23 2.61 4.35 6.96 27 2.96 3.70 6.66 29 3.45 3.45 6.90 30 4.00 3.33 7.33 When the firm produces 27 units of output, for example, the firm's variable costs from Table 1 are $80. The average variable cost per unit of output is therefore $80/27
= $2.96, as reported in Table 2 . The fixed cost corresponding to 27 units of output is $100; therefore, the average fixed cost per unit of output is
$100/27 = $3.70. The total cost of 27 units of output is $180; so, the average total cost is $180/27 = $6.66. Graphical depiction of costs. The
variable, fixed, and total costs reported in Table 1 are shown in Figure 1 . The marginal cost reported in Table 1 along with the average variable, average fixed, and average total costs reported in Table 2 are shown in the graph in Figure 1 (b). Cost Curves When costs are depicted graphically, they are referred to as cost curves. Figures 1 (a) and 1 (b) reveal some of the interesting relationships that exist among the various cost curves. Note first that the
total cost curve is just the vertical summation of the variable cost curve and the fixed
cost curve. This also holds true for the average total cost curve, which is just the vertical
summation of the average variable cost curve and the average fixed cost curve. Second, note the
relationship between the marginal cost curve and the total and variable cost curves. The marginal
cost curve reaches its minimum at the inflection point of the
total and variable cost curves. This should not be surprising because the slope of the total and variable cost curves reveals
the rate at which the firm's costs change as output increases, which is precisely what marginal cost measures. Finally, notice that the marginal cost
curve intersects both the average variable cost curve and the average total cost curve at the minimum points of both curves.
This is in accordance with the marginal-average rule, which states that when marginal cost lies below average cost, average cost is falling. When
marginal cost lies above average cost, average cost is rising. It follows, then, that the marginal cost curve will intersect the average variable and average
total cost curves at each of these curves' minimum points.TABLE 1 Firm Output and Costs TABLE 2 Firm Output and Average Costs Figure 1